wricaplogo

Overview: Tue, May 14

Alan Blinder

Thu, September 08, 1994
Wall Street Journal Interview

What got us into trouble in the '60s was overly expansionary fiscal policy due to the Vietnam War. Everybody knows that. A large part of the trouble of the 1970s was due to supply shocks -- food, oil. It wasn't the only thing, but it was a very major shock. It wasn't due to monetary policy errors. I don't mean to say the Fed was flawless. The goal is to get the unemployment to around the natural rate and not to overshoot. If you do that, you're not going to make an inflationary error. Mistakes will be made. We're not tuning a precision instrument here. Sometimes you'll accidentally be too tight. Sometimes you'll accidentally be too loose. That doesn't lead to any secular creep in inflation.

Thu, September 08, 1994
Wall Street Journal Interview

I don't see why obvious facts about the economy shouldn't be said in public. It's part of reducing the mystery of this business. I'm not a big believer in mystery.

Wed, September 25, 1996
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

I remember very well a conversation I had with a very smart financial reporter shortly after I left the Fed. He said that he has learned over the years to ignore what the Fed says and watch what it does. I had to concede that he was right, but it troubled me a great deal that the two would be so different. In my view, they should be a matched pair.

Wed, September 25, 1996
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

So, to me, the argument for the Fed's dual mandate is both straightforward and convincing. The central bank exists to serve society. The public cares deeply about fluctuations in the pace of economic activity. And well-executed monetary policy has the power to mitigate fluctuations in employment. As the mathematicians say, "QED." Fortunately, almost all central bankers accept this argument nowadays, notwithstanding a great deal of misleading rhetoric to the contrary.

Wed, September 25, 1996
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

I think it would surprise most of you to learn that a time-and-motion study of the daily lives of Federal Reserve Governors would reveal that most of their efforts are devoted to bank regulatory issues, broadly defined. Most of this business is routine, extremely familiar, and intensely interesting to the banking industry, and totally unknown, deeply obscure, and generally quite boring to everybody else in society.

Fri, August 25, 2006
Jackson Hole Symposium

One Greenspanian innovation that surely can (and, we believe, will) survive Greenspan’s reign is his choice of monetary policy instrument. Greenspan focused—or perhaps we should say refocused—the Fed on setting the federal funds rate. More important, however, he has made it clear since 1993 that he thinks of the Fed as trying to set the real federal funds rate and, more particularly, the deviation of that rate from its “neutral” level...

The concept of the neutral (real) rate of interest dates back to Wicksell (1898), who called it the “natural” interest rate, meaning the real rate dictated by technology and time preference. In modern New Keynesian models of monetary policy, it often appears as the real rate of interest that makes the output gap equal to zero, which makes the difference between r and r* a natural indicator of the stance of monetary policy.  As with the natural rate of unemployment, there are also many ways to estimate the neutral rate of interest. Some propose measuring the neutral interest rate as the rate at which inflation is neither rising nor falling (Blinder, 1998); others use low-frequency movements in output and real interest rates (Laubach and Williams, 2005); and still others prefer to “back it  out” of an economic model as the real rate that would obtain under price flexibility (Neiss and Nelson, 2003). 
 

[1]  This concept first appeared in his July 1993 Humphrey-Hawkins testimony (Greenspan, 1993), and was controversial at the time. There, Greenspan referred to judging the stance of monetary policy “by the level of real short-term interest rates” and noted that “the central issue is their relationship to an equilibrium interest rate,” which he defined as the rate that “would keep the economy at its production potential over time.”

Fri, August 25, 2006
Jackson Hole Symposium

What follows is not ours or anyone else’s list of the most cherished central banking principles; we do not wish either to denigrate Bagehot or to displace him. Rather, it is our distillation of economists and central bankers can and should take away as the Greenspan legacy, that is, it is what Alan Greenspan could have told us—if he had chosen to do so.

Two principles that clearly were important in guiding Greenspan’s decisions do not appear on our list: the concern for price stability and the importance of establishing and maintaining credibility. We omit these principles not because we think them unimportant but because they are so obvious and widely shared that they cannot reasonably be said to define the specific legacy of Alan Greenspan.

Principle No. 1: Keep your options open. Academic economists are fond of writing about the conceptual virtues of rules, precommitment devices, and the like. Greenspan, the great practitioner, is unsympathetic. Rather, as we have noted, he believes that the economy changes far too much and far too fast for conventional econometric tools ever to pin down its structure with any accuracy and, for this reason, committing to a rule for monetary policy or even to a fixed response to a specific shock is dangerous. In this context, the concept of option value should perhaps be interpreted literally: In a world of great uncertainty, the value of keeping your options open is high. And that, presumably, makes it wise to move gradually. Alan Greenspan certainly acts as if he believes that.

Principle No. 2: Don’t let yourself get trapped in doctrinal straitjackets. Similarly, one of Greenspan’s great strengths has been flexibility. He has never let himself get locked in to any economic doctrine (e.g., monetarism), any treasured analytical approach (e.g., the expectational Phillips curve), nor any specific parameter value (e.g., the 6% natural rate). Indeed, you might argue that Greenspan, the empiricist, has shown limited interest in doctrines of any kind. He has also been known to change his mind—without, of course, saying so!—on certain issues (e.g., transparency). The downside of all this flexibility is that nobody knows what “the Greenspan model” of the economy is; that will not be part of his legacy. But the upside is more important. To paraphrase the wise words of James Duesenberry in another context, Greenspan will not “follow a straight line to oblivion.” That’s a good principle for any central banker to remember.

Principle No. 3: Avoid policy reversals. Greenspan believes that rapid changes of direction are damaging to the reputations of both the central bank and its leader, and might also cause volatility in markets. This, of course, both helps explain the importance of “option value” and provides a reason for monetary policymakers to move gradually once they start moving, for there is no going back—at least not for a while.

Principle No. 4: Forecasts and models, though necessary, are unreliable. Greenspan is deeply skeptical about the accuracy of economic forecasts—a result, perhaps, of a lifetime of seeing forecasts go awry. So he is constantly examining what’s going on in the economy right now and trying to figure out which of these developments will be lasting and which will be fleeting. This, we believe, is another reason why Greenspan prefers to move gradually once he starts moving. Like an attentive nurse, he is constantly taking the economy’s temperature. Similarly, even though many staff resources at the Fed are devoted to building models of the economy, Greenspan treats these models as but a small part of the information set 85 relevant for monetary policy. He sees some economists as confusing models with reality, and he doesn’t make that mistake. Nor does he rely on models for forecasting.

Principle No. 5: Act preemptively when you can. A paradox is defined as an apparent contradiction. Here’s one: While skeptical of forecasts (see Principle No. 4), Greenspan has nonetheless been credited with the idea of “preemptive” monetary policy—which, of course, entails acting on the basis of a forecast.109 While the uniqueness of the idea is sometimes exaggerated, it is true that Greenspan has frequently argued that the Fed should tighten preemptively to fight inflation or ease preemptively to forestall economic weakness—and has done so prominently on a number of occasions. This attitude contrasts with traditional central banking practice, which often moves too late against either inflation, unemployment, or both.

Principle No. 6: Risk management works better in practice than formal optimization procedures—especially as a safeguard against very adverse outcomes. In Greenspan’s view, economists don’t know enough to compute and follow “optimal” monetary policies, and we delude ourselves if we pretend we can. So robustness, and probably even satisficing, rather than optimizing (as that term is normally understood) are among the touchstones of the Greenspan standard. As we have seen, Greenspan has characterized himself as practicing the art of risk management— somewhat like a banker does. And like a commercial or investment banker, a central banker must be constantly on guard against very adverse scenarios, even if they have low probabilities of occurring. So, for example, Greenspan’s preoccupation with the dangers of deflation in 2002 and 2003 was seen by some observers as excessive, given the actual risk. But he was determined not to allow the Fed to follow the Bank of Japan into the zero-nominal-interest-rate trap.

Principle No. 7: Recessions should be avoided and/or kept short, as should periods of growth below potential. It may seem silly even to list this principle, much less to credit it to Greenspan—until you remember some of the most cherished traditions in central banking. While he has certainly enjoyed his share of good luck, we think it is no accident that there have been only two mild recessions on his long watch and that he is now in the process of attempting his fourth soft landing (note the adjective). The Greenspan standard internalizes the fact that society finds recessions traumatic; it therefore takes the Fed’s dual mandate seriously. When the economy has appeared to need more running room—in the late 1990s and, one might say, into 2004—Greenspan was less then eager to withdraw the punch bowl.

Principle No. 8: Most oil shocks should not cause recessions. As we have noted, up to the present time, almost all oil shocks—defined as sharp increases in the relative price of oil—have been temporary. And a short-run change in a relative price is not a good reason to have a recession. (See Principle No. 7.) By focusing on core rather than headline inflation, the Greenspan standard has not only used a more reliable indicator of future headline inflation but has also avoided the error of piling tight money on top of an adverse oil shock—which is a pretty sure recipe for recession.

Principle No. 9: Don’t try to burst bubbles; mop up after. First of all, you might fail—or bring down the economy before you burst the bubble. (Again, see Principle No. 7.) Furthermore, bubble bursting is not part of the Fed’s legal 87 mandate, and it might do more harm than good. Finally, the “mop up after” strategy, which may require large injections of central bank liquidity, seems to work pretty well.

Principle No. 10: The short-term real interest rate, relative to its neutral value, is a viable and sensible indicator of the stance of monetary policy. The idea of using the real short rate as the main instrument of monetary policy appears to have been a Greenspan innovation, one which was highly controversial at the time (how can the Fed control a real rate?) but has since found its way into scores of scholarly papers. While the neutral rate can never be known with certainty, the potential errors in estimating it seem no larger than for other candidate instruments. (Who would like to guess the optimal growth rate for M2?)

Principle No. 11: Set your aspirations high, even if you can’t achieve all of them. Sure, a central banker needs to be realistic about what monetary policy can accomplish. (See Principles No. 4 and 6.) But that is not a reason to set low aspirations. Even if an attempt at fine tuning fails (as happened in 1988-1989), it is likely to do more good than harm as long as it is done gradually and with flexibility (see Principle No. 1). And if it succeeds (as in 1994-1995 and perhaps in 1999-2000), society benefits enormously. While the Jackson Hole conference was going on, a poster in the lobby of the hotel warned guests that “A Fed Bear Is a Dead Bear.” Alan Greenspan has definitely been a Fed bull, and that may be one of the chief secrets behind his remarkable longevity and success. 

Fri, August 25, 2006
Jackson Hole Symposium

Greenspan’s initial image was not that of an inflation “dove.” In fact, he was typically portrayed by the media as an inflation “hawk” in the early years of his chairmanship. It took the media almost a decade to catch on to the fact that, relative to the center of gravity of the FOMC, Greenspan was actually a dove—which became crystal clear when he repeatedly restrained a committee that was eager to  raise rates in 1996-1997.  But it should have been evident earlier. After all, over the first eight years of the Greenspan chairmanship, inflation was consistently above the Fed’s likely long-run target, and yet the core CPI inflation rate fell by less than one percentage point.  That hardly looks like the handiwork of an “inflation nutter.”

Thu, March 20, 2008
Washington Post Interview

Alan Blinder, a Princeton University economics professor who was vice chairman of the Fed under Greenspan in the mid-1990s, says that the delay in raising rates in 2003-04 was a "minor blemish" on Greenspan's "stellar" record managing monetary policy. But Blinder says that he would give the former chairman "poor marks" for bank supervision, another key role of the Fed.

Blinder said that Greenspan "brushed off" warnings -- most notably from fellow Fed governor Ned Gramlich -- about mortgage abuses and dangers.

"Lending standards were being horribly relaxed, and the Fed should have done something about that, not to mention about deceptive and in some cases fraudulent practices," Blinder said. "This was a corner of the credit markets that was allowed to go crazy. It was populated by a lot of people with minimal financial literacy who were being sold bills of goods by mortgage salesmen."

Tue, May 27, 2008
New York Times

Ben is one of these guys who is outwardly calm and has inner stomachaches.

He’s under a tremendous amount of strain.

Fri, August 22, 2008
Jackson Hole Symposium

One day, a little Dutch boy was walking home when he noticed a small leak in a dike that protected the town. He started to stick his finger in the hole. But then he remembered the moral hazard lessons he had learned in school.  "Wait a minute," he thought.  “The companies that built this dike did a terrible job.  They don’t deserve a bailout, and doing so would just encourage more shoddy construction. Besides, the dumb people who live here should never have built their homes on a flood plain.” So the boy continued on his way home. Before he arrived, the dike burst and everyone for miles around drowned - including the little Dutch boy.

Perhaps you've heard the Fed's alternative version of the story.  In this kindler, gentler version, the little Dutch boy, somewhat desperate and worried about the horrors of a flood, stuck his finger in the dike and held it there until help arrived. It was painful and not guaranteed to work - and the little boy would rather have been doing other things. But he did it anyway. And all the foolish people who lived behind the dike were saved from the error of their ways.